Back
David Bollier: Think like a Commoner (2014, New Society Publishers) 5 stars

A new world based on fairness, participation, accountability is closer than you think if you …

There is just one significant flaw in the tragedy [of the commons] parable. It does not accurately describe a commons. Hardin's fictional scenario sets forth a system that has no boundaries around the pasture, no rules for managing it, no punishments for overuse and no distinct community of users. But that is not a commons. ... A commons requires that there be a community willing to act as a conscientious steward of a resource

Think like a Commoner by  (Page 29)

@Kantolope

It seems like almost nobody who references Hardin has actually read The Tragedy of the Commons.

http://www.eeescience.utoledo.edu/Faculty/Mayer/reading/The%20Tragedy%20of%20the%20Commons,%20by%20Garrett%20Hardin%20(1968).htm

His point was not that commons don't work, but that they need effective regulation to avoid the titular problem. These days, following Ostrom, we fold that regulation into what a commons *is*, but this definition wasn't in widespread use when Hardin wrote the essay in the 1960s.

@strypey This.

Hardin may not have been describing a historically-accurate Commons. What he was describing though was a view towards (usually corporate / commercial) exploitation of common resources, without adequate regulation. Privatised profits, socialised costs. That is what he opposed.

Virtually all the present-day rewriting of his TotC essay is actually arguing for precisely what he was calling for, whilst trying to throw up a disagreement-which-doesn't-actually-exist based on semantics and misrepresentations.

@Kantolope

1/

@strypey

I read much of Hardin's works, saw him lecture a few times, and even met with him once. I'm not entirely certain of the present take on his immigration stance --- much of that seem either based on 1) associations with others, 2) his later writings (post 1990 or so), and a pretty revisionist take on his earlier (1960s -- 1990) writings. That critique does not seem to have appeared at any point up to the 1990s, or even during his life so far as I'm aware, though I'll grant that views, perspectives, and sensibilities have changed tremendously, my own included.

I do believe that there are people and organisations Hardin was affiliated with which did eventually emerge as racist and anti-immigrant. Again. there were strong shifts in viewpoints and specific statements over time.

But as of the 1968 essay itself ... I think you'd be hard-pressed to make the case.

@Kantolope

2/end/

@dredmorbius @strypey @Kantolope

He writes that "the world's resources are inequitably distributed" and hints at the fact that developed nations stole a lot of them, but insists that "We cannot remake the past", his excuse being that poor people reproduce too quickly.

But we know that fertility reduces as income increases, both at individual levels and national levels. US fertility decreased as wealth increased.

@dredmorbius @strypey @Kantolope

So if we want to encourage India and China to reduce population growth, the logical way to do it is to raise their standard of living. But his solution is to hoard the resources, keep 'em poor, and watch 'em die.

He concludes that we need to control immigration "if we wish to save at least some parts of the world from environmental ruin." But this ignores that it's the rich nations driving our environmental crisis, not the poor ones.

@mathew I'd roll back a little bit further:

Resources and carrying capacity are ultimately finite.

That to me is his core and foundational premise.

I'm revisiting his essays (I've not read them since the late 1980s / early 1990s for the most part). There are a few further assumptions which may well be questionable:

  • Resource distribution is inequitable: valid

  • We can't rewrite the past: arguable, though from a pragmatic basis ... there's some truth to this. Look at the rather simpler question of, say, progressive and equitable taxation.

  • That population is not a global problem, but on of local ecosystems and support. This is another key point on which much of his arguments hinge, and it may well be incorrect, as humans overloading carrying capacity does not contain itself in many regards: CO2 emissions, regional unrest, disease, financial dislocations, disrupting globalised trade and commerce (on which many livelihoods, and …

@mathew There's another buried assumption in his argument as well, and it's one I don't think he explicitly states.

It's the question of exponential growth --- growth at some constant percentage rate. That will result in tremendous growth over time, and you can approximate the doubling time with 70/r, where r is the periodic percentage growth. So 2% growth rate -> doubling in 35 periods, 10% -> doubling in 7 periods, 35% -> 2 periods. Roughly.

Population growth is expressed as an annual percentage rate. It's expoential.

Wealth differentials are a constant. So if the wealthy countries of the world are on balance 10x richer than the poorest, that's about 3.3 doubling periods. If they're 100x richer, it's about 6.6 periods. A small difference in relative population growth makes up for a huge difference in relative wealth.

But we also live in a world in which net GDP is …